Paying Skilled Workers More Would Create More Skilled Workers
When
computers made their way into workplaces, in the 1980s, typists had a
problem. As computers replaced traditional typewriters, the skills of
typists who did not know how to work with a word processor grew
obsolete. Nevertheless, few would argue that information technology
permanently increased unemployment. Although the unemployment
rate did spike in the 1980s, it eventually went back down again, so
the average unemployment rate in the 1990s was similar to
the rate in the 1970s. The labor force adjusted to a new technology
replacing an older one.
In
the wake of the 2008 financial crisis, there was
a lively debate among policy
makersand academics about
whether a similar gap “between
the skills workers have and the skills businesses say they need”
contributed to the increase in unemployment. Research has since shown
that the skills gap has a cyclical effect
on unemployment, explaining as much as one-third
of the increase in unemployment following
the Great Recession.
It
is usually taken for granted that the skills gap is a problem of
skills supply, and public concerns often focus on a lack
of STEM skills and soft
skills.
So proposed solutions tend to involve reforming education and
worker training
programs.
The most popular approach has been to reduce
tuition fees for
selective fields of study, usually STEM majors.
However,
I argue that this view is not correct. Research that
I and my colleagues have conducted suggests that
the skills gap persists mainly because employers are unwilling or
unable to pay market price for the skills they require.
There
are three possible reasons for why a skills gap exists. First,
workers do not adjust to changes in the demand by acquiring new
skills. Second, employers do not take the supply of skills into
account when they make hiring decisions. Third, employers do not take
into account the relative shortage or abundance of particular skills
when they set wages. Using U.S. data on job
finding and filling rates, wages,
andprofits across
states and industries since 1979, we measured the contribution of
each of these three reasons on mismatch unemployment. We found
that wage
setting is the main reason why
workers don’t have the skills employers are looking for.
The
workforce can adjust to changes in the demand for skills by acquiring
new skills, through training, or by replacing older workers with
younger ones who have up-to-date skills. For example, an
unemployed typist looking for work in the 1980s could learn how to
use a computer or fill a vacant position left by another typist who
moved on to another job or retired.
Firms can
also respond to changes in the supply of skills. In the 1980s, for
instance, organizations could train their typists in word processing
or keep some typist positions open. While hiring less-skilled workers
hurts a firm’s productivity, the data shows that companies still
did this in order to take advantage of the fact that hiring these
workers is so much cheaper.
Our
data shows that these kinds of adjustments do indeed happen, and that
they happen fast enough to prevent unemployment from going up. There
aren’t many occupations that are both easy
to find and high-paying,
which is what we would expect if the workforce were not adjusting and
companies were struggling to find talent. Similarly, there are few
jobs that are easy
to fill and that generate high profitsfor
the company.
Yet
the skills gap remains, because the adjustments that workers and
firms make will only eliminate the gap if wages reflect the
relative supply and demand for various skills across occupations. But
our data shows that this is not happening: Many jobs in
industries that generate high profits (retail trade, educational
services, mining, and forestry) tend to pay low wages and are
therefore unattractive to workers, whereas jobs in industries that
pay higher wages (finance, computer and electronics manufacturing,
paper and printing) are not
very profitable.
Imagine
that a particular set of skills — say, STEM skills — enables
workers to be particularly productive but their pay does not go up to
reflect this higher productivity. It is not surprising that workers
do not acquire more of these skills, since they do not reap any of
the benefits of their increased productivity. In the UK, for
instance, less
than half of
STEM graduates work in scientific occupations, and there is no wage
premium for having a STEM degree in other occupations.
On
the other hand, firms are more interested in hiring workers with
these STEM skills, as they are very productive and cheap. Thus
companies open lots of vacancies for STEM positions but find
it very difficult to fill them.
Companies
often advocate for better education to fix the skills gap, but our
results indicate that this is unlikely to work for a simple reason:
Students have a choice about what skills they acquire in school and
how they use these skills in the labor market. Encouraging
universities to educate more physicists and engineers will not make a
difference if these additional STEM graduates then choose to work for
investment banks that offer higher salaries.
Unfortunately,
our research does not provide an explanation for why wages
do not reflect relative labor market conditions across occupations or
skills.
However,
the data clearly indicates that wages for workers with scarce skills
are too low compared to wages for workers with a more abundant skill
set. It would seem that this provides a profitable opportunity for
companies that are able to be flexible in their compensation policy.
By paying more for certain skills, an employer would have no trouble
attracting workers with those skills in sufficient quantity and
quality, giving the company an undeniable edge over its
competitors.
Harvard Business Review
Paying Skilled Workers More Would Create More Skilled Workers
Reviewed by Unknown
on
Friday, May 20, 2016
Rating:
No comments: